Forest and tourism: economic evaluation and management features under sustainable multifunctionality
iForest - Biogeosciences and Forestry, Volume 2, Issue 5, Pages 192-197 (2009)
doi: https://doi.org/10.3832/ifor0514-002
Published: Oct 15, 2009 - Copyright © 2009 SISEF
Research Articles
Collection/Special Issue: EFI 2008 Annual Conference Week - Orvieto (Italy)
Adaptation of Forest Landscape to Environmental Changes
Guest Editors: Giuseppe Scarascia Mugnozza (CRA - Rome, Italy)
Abstract
The ways in which forests have been used and managed by man have been modified substantially over time in relation to both changes in the economic and social needs of communities and the visions of the world that these have embraced. In recent times, as regards the flows of utility guaranteed by forests, increasing interest has been focused on recreational aspects of the landscape. Such interest derives from both the importance, highlighted by numerous studies, of this aspect and its connection with tourism. The latter phenomenon is undergoing strong growth and is able to trigger important processes of local development. Within this framework, the present study advances some preliminary considerations on the relationships which, from the standpoint of sustainable local development, exist between possible types of tourism and alternative methods of forest management. To this end, it first explores some characteristics of the forest landscape and their possible economic evaluation, in the light of the attributes of excludability and rivalry in consumption. The study then discusses the possible economic role of tourism and the contribution that a suitable forest landscape can make to the sector’s development. Finally, it sets in context modes of forest management and alternative types of tourism development.
Keywords
Sustainable forest management, Tourism, Landscape, Public goods, Local development
Introduction
In the course of time, modes of forest use and management have changed greatly in relation to the evolution in the socio-economic needs of various communities ([26]), as well as in relation to the world views which influence those communities ([20], [34]). Specifically, after a period of time in which forests were a source of numerous useful products for local populations ([19]), they have now become the source of a single product, namely timber. More recently, the demand on forests has progressively diversified to include new aspects, for example, carbon fixing, giving different importance to functions once taken for granted, like the forest’s role in the water cycle ([26]). Different social groups also sometimes assign contrasting significance to the forest itself ([22]).
As a consequence of the above-mentioned evolution the basic concepts of forest management have also changed. This is because they can be considered as nothing other than ’the formulation at the scientific level of social issues which have, over time, been outlined ([35]). In parallel with concepts and management types, change has also taken place in the application methods which attempt to put the previous implications into practice. The result is that, at present, “those who are interested in forest management are required to have a broader vision of forestry so that many different social needs can be satisfied” ([40]).
The emphasis on various economic, social and environmental functions is increasing at a time when the income derived from the use of wood is decreasing. In consequence, there is a clear abandonment of forest cultivation with major negative consequences ([34]), as well as a search for alternative income sources. The latter are payments which derive either directly or indirectly from the positive externalities of forests. These revenues are obtained through public incentives or through mechanisms which obtain payment from the users themselves.
Although great efforts have been made within the framework of sustainable development to lay down universal guidelines for management methods able to ensure the maximisation of the social benefits produced by the forest itself, none have so far succeeded.
Many factors hamper identification of these guidelines: for example, the variability of forest ecosystems, the changes (in many cases very rapid) in the various stakeholders, each of them with different objectives in forestry management, the difficulties in evaluating the economic value of the various flows of utility that a forest produces. At the same time, other difficulties derive from the fact that, in economic terms, the various goods obtained from a forest have different characteristics.
Amongst the flows of utility that a forest generates, a key role is played by the landscape-recreational aspect. Indeed, according to the FAO ([14]), 72% of European forests perform this function, which is also closely related to tourism, and this, as we know, is a growing phenomenon that can trigger important processes of local development ([38]).
This paper discusses the relationship between forests and tourism within the framework of sustainable development. To this end, the argument has been divided into six parts. The first is an in-depth investigation of some of the landscape’s characteristics and their classification in relation to the attributes of excludability and rivalry in consumption. The second part reports some economic evaluations of forests’ landscape-recreational value. The third part is an analysis of several instruments which can be implemented to transform the landscape externality into a source of income for those who manage the forests. The fourth part discusses the possible economic role of tourism from the perspective of local development and in the organisational models of tourist systems. The fifth part offers some considerations on forest management. Part six concludes.
Landscape components and utility flows
It is well known that the various utility flows that forests produce exhibit different characteristics in relation to the attributes of rivalry and excludability, which, when considered jointly, produce clusters of goods with similar economic characteristics. If we consider these two attributes and examine their most recent evolution, we can understand how a substantial change has come about at a general level within the forest. In the Western world, consideration of the forest as a source of private good, such as timber, has gradually given way to its increasing importance in the supply of public and semi-public goods. In fact, up until fifty years ago, forestry developed in a way in which the primary interest was in wood production, while the cost of labour was low; today that has changed, so it is necessary to take advantage of the natural opportunities in a way which at the same time maximises mass production and quality in the least expensive way ([34]).
Among those opportunities is the forest’s crucial role in formation of the landscape. Nevertheless, implicit recognition of the forest’s role in regard to the landscape has not always been followed by coherent policies for the management of forests.
The importance of the landscape is obvious, but it is more difficult to give it a universal definition. In fact, the term “landscape” traverses many fields of knowledge ([30]), is susceptible to a variety of meanings ([11]), and allows different ideas and knowledge to be connected with one another ([8]). Moreover, the concept that the rural landscape is a “permanent creative process” ([42]) implies on the one hand that analysis of the landscape must take account of the factors which produce the landscape transformation, and on the other that the evaluation must be performed in historical and dynamic terms, instead of being restricted to a static analysis based solely on aesthetics.
In this regard, [46], when referring to the rural landscape, and therefore implicitly to the role of the forest landscape, maintain that ’People are shopping in the landscape’. In this framework it can be argued that if the landscape is an utility for those who enjoy it, the relative demand for it becomes quite complex and “…can be satisfied by a heterogeneous mosaic of landscape types, characterized by variable modalities and intensities of man’s interventions, but with forms and functions equally desirable in different social contexts” ([39]).
From the point of view of demand, the value of rural landscape can be considered as the sum of three main components: scenic (or landscape) value, recreational value, and nostalgic (or evocative) value. Unlike the first two, the last component is not connected to direct use of the good ([10]).
Scenic value, combined with aesthetic quality, is in its turn composed of various elements, which some authors ([39], [45]) identify as quality, normality, peculiarity, diversity, stability, whereas others ([25]) consider the relevant elements to be coherence, legibility, complexity, mystery. Finally, in a few cases ([44]), emphasis is placed on the role which specific elements may have in modifying the level of appreciation that a certain landscape can arouse.
Therefore, the complexity of the mosaic which makes up the landscape is such that even in economic terms it can be considered as a group of goods rather than a precisely identifiable product. This situation applies to other flows of utility produced by forests as well. Consider the case of biodiversity. The result is that, even in relation to the attributes of excludability and rivalry, different “products” of the forest can be classified into different clusters, as illustrated in Tab. 1.
Tab. 1 - Flows of utility generated by the forest. Source: Our elaboration on [31].
Goods | Non-rival | Congestible | Rival |
---|---|---|---|
Non-excludable | Purely public goods: - CO2 fixation - elimination of pollutants - landscape (non-use values) |
Open access resources: - landscape (in resources-based recreational areas) |
- |
Excludable to outsiders of a community |
Local public goods: - hydro-geologic protection - regulation of the water cycle - landscape (scenic component) |
Common property resources: - hunting |
- |
Excludable | Toll goods: - landscape (option values) |
Club goods | Private goods: - timber - landscape (in recreational areas user-oriented) |
In almost all cases, the interaction between tourist activity and the forest landscape operates through consideration of the latter as a support for recreational activities. It is accordingly useful to start by attempting to classify the roles that a forest landscape may perform within different types of recreational areas. For this purpose, only use values will be considered, which means the recreational and scenic components of the landscape.
It is necessary to reclassify these components in the light of work by [5]. Depending on one’s perspective, forests can be wholly or partially user- oriented or resource-based recreational areas, or they may even assume the function of a background.
In the first case, the forest (or elements of it) becomes a specific resource with which to attract the attention of tourists. An example is provided by acrobatic parks. The area occupied is usually relatively small, and it is possible to gain exclusivity of its use and utilise it for tourism initiatives which do not belong to a system. In the second case, the forest constitutes a generic resource for tourism, even if it is not always replaceable. It can be regarded as an element of the scenario in which different elements of the supply are located in order to make up the tourist destination. The area occupied is generally very large but delimited by sufficiently identifiable borders. It is not possible to have use exclusivity and there may be cases of congestion. In the third case, the forest is not perceived as a decisive element in the tourist supply, although it is an important factor in determining the overall attractiveness of the tourist destination. The area occupied is generally large, situated away from the central zones of the tourist destination and not clearly delimited to the observer. It is obviously not possible to have exclusivity, but cases of congestion are unlikely.
Economic evaluation of the landscape-recreational component of the forest
The bulk of research conducted to give a value to the landscape-recreational function of forests - in order to simplify the complex analytical framework and to overcome the difficulties of assigning weights to the various components - has sought to obtain the values attributed to forests by visitors. The surveys carried out for this purpose are numerous. In Italy alone, during the period between 1982 and 2005 ([35], [30]), at least 40 surveys of this type were conducted. There are, however, far fewer monetary evaluations of the landscape as such: for example, Tempesta & Thiene ([44]) count 39 surveys on this topic relative to Europe and only a few of them concern forests.
The findings of the above-mentioned studies can be generalised only with caution, given that the scenario in which the research is conducted is of great relevance. Amongst other things, owing to the survey methodology used in many cases only the value per visit is determined with no reference made to values by surface area. This obviously makes the values obtained more difficult to use for management purposes. In fact, it has been emphasised that preferences regarding the same landscape vary considerably if it is presented to the respondents as existing or as deriving from a potential transformation process ([22]).
The availability of a significant number of surveys, however, allows one to gain an order of magnitude of the landscape value of forests. For example, by analysing 38 surveys conducted in Italy between 1982 and 2006, and stating the values in 2007 prices, one can determine that the value for each visit varies between 1.26 and 32.88 euros, with an average value of 8.21 euros. This average is influenced by a few particularly large values. In fact, almost half of the values found fell between three and five euros per visit.
The values obtained in the surveys mentioned above are probably overestimated in respect of the average values to be found in all forests, owing to the fact that the surveys were probably conducted in areas of particular importance to the aspect analysed. Nevertheless, they are interesting values, as confirmed by comparison of the landscape- recreational and the timber production values of the same forests. Similar comparison can be made with regard to the forests of some Mediterranean countries (see Tab. 2 and Tab. 3 for Italian forests).
Tab. 2 - Value of timber production and landscape-recreational function (euro/ha). Source: Our calculations based on [28].
Country | Industrial roundwood |
Firewood | Recreation value of parks |
Recreation value of forests |
---|---|---|---|---|
Croatia | 75.8 | 12.7 | 450.0 | - |
France | 72.8 | 16.4 | - | 114.5 |
Greece | 8.4 | 5.1 | 12.0 | - |
Italy | 24.3 | 26.4 | - | 19.7-48.8 |
Portugal | 130.5 | 11.3 | - | 4.9 |
Spain | 27.8 | 1.5 | 95.0 | - |
Slovenia | 76.0 | 10.3 | - | - |
Tab. 3 - Value of timber production and landscape-recreational function (euro/ha). Source: (a) [35], (b) [16], (c) [27].
- | Oulx Municipality (a) | Trento Province (b) | Friuli Region (c) |
---|---|---|---|
Timber production | 40.01 | 94.47 | 137.4 |
Utilised production | n.a. | 45.86 | n.a. |
Landscape recreational value | 55.16 | 47.94 | 158.9 |
Finally, regarding the problems of management and local development, it is advisable to bear in mind an aspect of landscape- recreational values related to capital intensity. The landscape-recreational values appear high if we compare them with those related to timber production, but they are very low if we compare them with those guaranteed by alternative forms of land use. In order to produce adequate income for today’s needs, therefore, large surfaces are required for timber production. Such surfaces are not always available, either because the firms are too small or because they are not compatible with adequate local development, which requires a sufficient population density. Finally, alternative uses, even for tourism, may be of interest and may create conflicts in relation to the planned land use.
Instruments to internalise positive landscape externalities
The increasing economic weight of the forest in landscape-recreational terms is accompanied on the one hand by the growing importance of tourism within the European economic system, and on the other by the fact that those affected by utility flows produced by the forest are segments of the population increasingly distant from it.
This evolution has created numerous problems largely because of the simultaneous reduction in the profitability of the forest as a timber producer. This phenomenon has stimulated a search for alternative sources of income in order to prevent the abandonment of the forest which causes numerous environmental, economic and social problems in broad areas such as the alpine regions.
At the same time, this evolution obviously requires management methods and instruments which differ from those of the past and which may generate conflicts among different uses and among potential beneficiaries.
This consideration also applies to the landscape as a shared space in which different communities and individuals pursue a variety of goals, and with regard to which it is difficult, if not impossible, to identify property rights. The landscape can therefore become controversial and raise numerous issues, such as the methods used to allocate the resources necessary for its production, definition of the subjects entitled to decide such matters, and how those to be paid for their conservation should be compensated.
A pleasant landscape is a positive externality of human activity and, in our case, of forest activity. How a forest is managed greatly influences the degree of landscape appreciation. At the same time, timber production and the landscape represent a joint production. Generally speaking, improvement of the landscape function increases the costs of and/or reduces timber production, with a consequent fall in income for owners of the forests and, if other compensating factors do not come into play, impoverishment of the local population.
In order to identify suitable measures with which to quantify positive landscape externalities produced by the forest together with other public goods, we can proceed from two different starting-points. The first requires that there is a reward at least equal to the higher costs (or lower profits) that the forester receives from conserving a pleasant landscape. The second requires that landscape ’production’ be paid by an amount equal to that of the benefits produced. Of course the two solutions imply different evaluations of the propriety right connected with the natural good “landscape”
Without going further into this aspect, although it may be of some importance from an application perspective, we can state that the available economic policy tools can be grouped into three different sets of intervention methods.
The first seeks to internalise the positive externalities produced by obliging those who use them to pay for them. The second consists of compensatory interventions granted by a public body. The third operates within the framework of local development and uses instruments derived from the management of common property resources.
These three types of intervention are not always mutually exclusive; rather, they are complementary to each other, or better they can be used in function of the characteristics of the forest landscape considered and of the economic system in which the landscape is embedded. To illustrate this, below are some brief considerations on tourism within the local development process, as well as on the possible connection between the landscape and recreational activity with regard to tourism.
Tourism and local development
It is well known that tourism is not a well-defined production activity but rather an aggregate of services and activities from various economic sectors. The nature of the tourism product is extremely composite and complex ([9], [41]). It is characterised by a type of use related to the features of the environment and by the fact that the activities of several players form a system ([43]). At the same time, the impact that tourism itself produces is also systemic, given that the tourism industry tends to involve the entire economy of the territory in which it operates, with effects of a social, cultural and environmental nature ([4]).
Like many other sectors, tourism has undergone radical changes ([12], [18]). On the demand side, these changes have produced an increase in tourist interest in nature, and on the supply side, growing awareness that nature and territory are resources which must be managed sustainably and not indiscriminately ([18]).
It is evident that tourism can be an important factor in local development. For this to occur, however, three fundamental conditions must be in place ([41], [43]):
- presence of attractiveness factors, i.e., resources of various kinds able to stimulate demand;
- uniform vision of the area with a geographically identified territory;
- cooperation among the actors involved with a view to an integrated supply.
Nonetheless, tourism supply is often not structured in the best possible way. In fact, the configurations of the supply can be ([2]):
- sectorial (not systemic), when the relationships among the subjects involved are random and unplanned;
- weakly systemic, when the supply actors feel that they are part of a uniform body, even if it is only a “loosely coupled” one;
- strongly systemic, when the actors are connected in a local tourist supply system in which the relationships among the subjects involved are institutionally planned.
It is obvious that in the first case there is room for some tourist activities, but not for a tourist system. The different configurations are important, however, even for selecting the tools with which to internalise the benefits produced by the forest landscape, as shown in more detail below.
Different approaches to forest management
Awareness of the forest’s ability to perform many functions has led over the years to identification of various principles on which forest management should be based. In relation to the evolution of society’s needs, new management schemes have been developed for the purpose of multiple use management, multifunctional forest management, and ecosystem management.
Multiple use management ([15]) centres on cultivation techniques for the uses and the utilities that goods and services supplied by the forest provide for man. Some techniques of multiple use management are multi-purpose land use, multi-user forest management ([3]) and multi-beneficiary forest management. These last two variants have been devised to satisfy growing demand for participation in the planning of cultivation and use operations. Planning is no longer the exclusive task of forest technicians but now also involves the users or beneficiaries. In application of the previously-mentioned principles, two different cultivation techniques have been developed, one consisting of large-scale segregation ([36]), the other of complete integration and equal priorities ([7]). The former provides for zoning and for time segmentation in areas designed for a single prevalent use. The second envisages the simultaneous pursuit of all uses across the entire area. There is also an intermediate technique: small-scale segregation, which consists of designing small areas for single prevalent uses ([21]).
The goal of multifunctional forest management ([23]) is to optimise the functions of forests regardless of whether they are more or less useful for man. Compared with multiple use management, the time frame is wider. The management methods incorporating these principles are goal- oriented and they comprise so-called integrated forest management ([24], [13]). Unlike multi-user and multi-beneficiary forest management, when this method is used, the role of forest technicians becomes more important because they can only indirectly take the needs of different social actors into account. These principles underlie the wake theory ([26], [29]). In this case, it is believed that maximising timber production will bring improvements in all other functions, so that multi-functionality is consequently optimised.
In ecosystem management ([1]), the planning of cultivation is not restricted to single functions but considers the ecosystem in its entirety, including all possible existing interconnections. The management method incorporating these principles is based on continuously monitored and revised plans. Participation in the management process of all stakeholders is envisaged, and the attainable results are evaluated from the landscape standpoint.
Forest management, landscape and tourism
Forest management is therefore a way to maintain the balance of a complex system in which there are joint forms of production and goals and constraints which are partially conflicting. This conflict may arise within a forest system or even on a territorial scale with other economic agents operating in the same area. Therefore, if the purpose is to obtain efficiency and sustainability, it is essential to identify the relevant aspects and to use mutually consistent instruments. Of course, operating in this way requires bearing in mind the constraints which arise from the many objectives and players involved and which become much more incisive when the latter are numerous, whereas efficiency in achieving a single objective does not always represent a necessary condition for obtaining the global efficiency of the entire system.
If examination is restricted to aspects regarding the relationships among forest management, landscape and tourism, the following conclusions can be drawn.
In cases where the forest landscape represents a specific resource (as illustrated in section 5) for tourist activity, the solution for the internalisation of the positive externalities produced is of Coasian type; that is, it is based on introduction of entry tickets paid by users. This solution appears to be applicable to small forest areas, including those with particularly interesting natural features, or those in which major investments have produced specific infrastructures (for example, those relative to acrobatic parks). In this case, multiple use management appears to be the most suitable managerial method to adopt. The presence of conditions enabling reliance on specialisation and economies of scale suggests that, in the majority of cases, the technique of large-scale segregation should be employed. Less frequently, and in the context of cases in which the additional investments are extensive (for example, pay trails connecting panoramic points, presence of biodiversity, areas dedicated to the gathering of underbrush products, etc.), it may be advisable to employ the equal priorities technique, because this is based on principles of economy of scope. This course of action is also compatible with tourism initiatives which are relatively isolated and not integrated into a system (although it would be of greater advantage if they were).
When the forest landscape represents a background scenario, the solution can only be a compensation of public nature. Case studies on public intervention are too numerous and too well-known to require further analysis here. Suffice it to mention the measures put in place by the European Union. From the forest management standpoint, it seems reasonable to operate within the multifunctionality framework, given that the interest in conserving the landscape externality appears to be widespread, but without it being a decisive factor for any of the stakeholders involved and consequently of little relevance to the definition of forest management methods. This interest, moreover, is held not only by tourists and tourist operators but also by residents and, owing to conditions of reduced excludability and rivalry, one comes close to the situation of a purely public good. If there are no problems in guaranteeing the other forest functions, it is helpful to refer to the wake effect. Among other things, it can be argued that maximising the biomass will guarantee better coverage of the surface and consequently generate a better “background” effect. Finally, from the tourism system standpoint, the feature which best describes this is the presence of weak ties among the various actors involved.
When the landscape is a scenario, and not just a simple production input, and directly enters into the function of visitor utility, producing a trade-off between resource consumption and supply quality ([38]), it is necessary to use the forest for the purpose of local development. Participation by all actors in the definition of goals is absolutely necessary. In recent times, among the methods piloted in relation to the rural landscape in its entirety are those relating to management agreements and maintenance agreements in the English-speaking countries, and those relating to cultivation contracts in France. With reference to forests, we can mention Scotland and England. Some of the first schemes of this kind, however, have encountered problems ([47]). Among those specifically aimed at the forest world are the community forests ([6]) which arose from institutional planning and are characterised by intense participation. This approach appears very interesting because, when certain conditions are met ([37]), it is possible to revitalise old experiences of collective management regarding vast forest areas in many European countries. Moreover, it seems well-established ([17]) that different areas are subject to objective conditions (relating to the resource to be managed) and subjective conditions (relating to the users of the resource), which, according to Ostrom ([32], [33]), increase the likelihood that self-governing organisations will emerge to manage open access resources and influence the benefits attainable and the costs which must be incurred in order to obtain them. In this case, it seems preferable to plan an ecosystemic type of forest management by using the long-standing techniques of naturalistic forestry. This is a management method in which man is an active component of the ecosystem, undertaking the role of managing in order to maintain the ecosystem in a dynamic equilibrium. Obviously, this type of approach is possible only with organised tourism within a local system of tourist supply.
The three above-mentioned approaches are ideal models which are rather difficult to identify unequivocally in concrete situations. In the majority of cases, there will be situations in which the elements present will make it necessary to use several instruments simultaneously. In these cases, definition of the relative importance of the different goals and the capacity to use the appropriate instruments are of crucial importance to ensure the long duration of the chosen model management.
Concluding remarks
As with other positive externalities produced by forest management, with the also it is difficult to internalise the benefits produced. In this regard, the possibility of introducing forms of payment to use landscape services seems restricted to a relatively small number of specific situations. Somewhat commoner seem to be areas in which the principle of collective ownership can be applied and in which payment is not made directly by those who use the landscape but rather by actors (hoteliers, shopkeepers, service firms) that benefit from the presence of the tourists. In all other cases remuneration of the landscape externality can only derive from action by the state.
Whatever the case may be, it is necessary to ensure coherence between the mode of forest management, the type of tourism, and the characteristics of the model of local development which are to be pursued. This objective is not easy to achieve, given that it is pursued within a complex situation where, besides the importance of individual factors, account must be taken of the relations among them. It is also necessary to bear in mind that this is a dynamic context in which the speed with which it is necessary to operate is not the same for the various systems considered. Specifically, the time necessary to ensure that changes in forest management are sustainable may be much longer than the time that the other actors involved in local development are willing to accept. This may generate conflicts and the necessity to operate by applying the precautionary principle.
Finally, one must emphasise that coherence between forest management, tourism and local development requires suitable policies that, amongst other things, imply the income redistribution from the actors who benefit to those who bear the costs of creating pleasant and appreciated landscapes.
References
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Gscholar
Authors’ Info
Authors’ Affiliation
Corresponding author
Paper Info
Citation
Gios G, Clauser O (2009). Forest and tourism: economic evaluation and management features under sustainable multifunctionality. iForest 2: 192-197. - doi: 10.3832/ifor0514-002
Academic Editor
Marco Borghetti
Paper history
Received: May 08, 2009
Accepted: Sep 03, 2009
First online: Oct 15, 2009
Publication Date: Oct 15, 2009
Publication Time: 1.40 months
Copyright Information
© SISEF - The Italian Society of Silviculture and Forest Ecology 2009
Open Access
This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-Non Commercial 4.0 International (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.
Web Metrics
Breakdown by View Type
Article Usage
Total Article Views: 74902
(from publication date up to now)
Breakdown by View Type
HTML Page Views: 43715
Abstract Page Views: 2832
PDF Downloads: 27533
Citation/Reference Downloads: 29
XML Downloads: 793
Web Metrics
Days since publication: 5518
Overall contacts: 74902
Avg. contacts per week: 95.02
Article Citations
Article citations are based on data periodically collected from the Clarivate Web of Science web site
(last update: Feb 2023)
Total number of cites (since 2009): 8
Average cites per year: 0.53
Publication Metrics
by Dimensions ©
Articles citing this article
List of the papers citing this article based on CrossRef Cited-by.
Related Contents
iForest Similar Articles
Research Articles
Public participation GIS to support a bottom-up approach in forest landscape planning
vol. 6, pp. 347-352 (online: 29 August 2013)
Editorials
Adaptation of forest landscape to environmental changes
vol. 2, pp. 127 (online: 30 July 2009)
Technical Advances
Forest planning and public participation: a possible methodological approach
vol. 5, pp. 72-82 (online: 12 April 2012)
Research Articles
Public participation in sustainable forestry: the case of forest planning in Slovakia
vol. 7, pp. 414-422 (online: 19 May 2014)
Review Papers
Public participation: a need of forest planning
vol. 7, pp. 216-226 (online: 27 February 2014)
Review Papers
Payment for forest environmental services: a meta-analysis of successful elements
vol. 6, pp. 141-149 (online: 08 April 2013)
Technical Reports
Tourism innovation in the forestry sector: comparative analysis between Auckland Region (New Zealand) and Trentino (Italy)
vol. 5, pp. 262-271 (online: 24 October 2012)
Research Articles
Communicating spatial planning decisions at the landscape and farm level with landscape visualization
vol. 7, pp. 434-442 (online: 19 May 2014)
Research Articles
Implications of ecotourism development in protected areas: a study from Rema-Kalenga Wildlife Sanctuary, Bangladesh
vol. 3, pp. 23-29 (online: 22 January 2010)
Research Articles
Application of indicators network analysis to support local forest management plan development: a case study in Molise, Italy
vol. 5, pp. 31-37 (online: 27 February 2012)
iForest Database Search
Search By Author
Search By Keyword
Google Scholar Search
Citing Articles
Search By Author
Search By Keywords
PubMed Search
Search By Author
Search By Keyword